Micah Saul: This project is built on a hypoth­e­sis. There are moments in his­to­ry when the sta­tus quo fails. Political sys­tems prove insuf­fi­cient, reli­gious ideas unsat­is­fac­to­ry, social struc­tures intol­er­a­ble. These are moments of cri­sis.

Aengus Anderson: During some of these moments, great minds have entered into con­ver­sa­tion and torn apart inher­it­ed ideas, dethron­ing truths, com­bin­ing old thoughts, and cre­at­ing new ideas. They’ve shaped the norms of future gen­er­a­tions.

Saul: Every era has its issues, but do ours war­rant The Conversation? If they do, is it hap­pen­ing?

Anderson: We’ll be explor­ing these sorts of ques­tions through con­ver­sa­tions with a cross‐section of American thinkers, peo­ple who are cri­tiquing some aspect of nor­mal­i­ty and offer­ing an alter­na­tive vision of the future. People who might be hav­ing The Conversation.

Saul: Like a real con­ver­sa­tion, this project is going to be sub­jec­tive. It will fre­quent­ly change direc­tions, con­nect unex­pect­ed ideas, and wan­der between the tan­gi­ble and the abstract. It will leave us with far more ques­tions than answers because after all, nobody has a monop­oly on dream­ing about the future.

Anderson: I’m Aengus Anderson.

Saul: And I’m Micah Saul. And you’re lis­ten­ing to The Conversation.


Aengus Anderson: Are you ready to talk about mis­fits? Not like, the punk band, but—

Micah Saul: Damn. I was seri­ous­ly just about to start singing Last Caress.”

Anderson: Oh, you know one of their song names. You are so much fur­ther ahead of me.

Saul: [sings] I got some­thing to say…

Anderson: Let us nev­er speak of them again. No one’s going to take us seri­ous­ly now. And that’s prob­a­bly good.

Saul: Let’s talk about mis­fits. Or specif­i­cal­ly, let’s talk about the mis­fit econ­o­my.

Anderson: This con­ver­sa­tion is with Alexa Clay, and she’s in the process coau­thor­ing a book called The Misfit Economy, look­ing at pirates, hack­ers, gang­sters, pris­ons. All sorts of places in the under­ground, where peo­ple are dis­trib­ut­ing goods, mak­ing goods, con­sum­ing goods, very dif­fer­ent­ly.

Saul: Right. These weird black mar­kets, but also gray mar­ket economies that have arisen on the fringes of the main­stream mar­ket econ­o­my.

Anderson: Yeah. Typically, economies that have appeared in des­per­ate sit­u­a­tions. And I think a big part of the premise is of course that in those sit­u­a­tions you see a lot of inno­va­tion.

Saul: So, yes. Alexa Clay. As you said, she’s writ­ing this book about these economies. She also works for Ashoka Changemakers. And she’s a fair­ly pro­lif­ic writer, writ­ing pieces for Fast Company, Forbes, Wired, Guardian. And actu­al­ly, we saw her speak in New York when we were both there all those many moons ago.

Anderson: Yes. It was at WFMU’s Radiovision con­fer­ence, and she was talk­ing about pira­cy. We thought, Ah. That would be real­ly cool to bring into The Conversation.” You know, we’ve talked a lot about big­ger eco­nom­ic sys­tems. Let’s talk about these real­ly small, scrap­py eco­nom­ic sys­tems and see how do they change the con­ver­sa­tion. Do they? Or are they just cap­i­tal­ism writ small? Or greed and growth writ small. So let’s dive into it.


Alexa Clay: I think I’ve always tried to under­stand real­ly the ori­gins of things, and was very inter­est­ed [in] eco­nom­ic his­to­ry and real­ly see­ing eco­nom­ic his­to­ry as a way of com­bat­ing just how closed‐off our cur­rent ways of think­ing around the econ­o­my have become. And so I looked it ideas from the 17th and 18th cen­tu­ry. You know, ear­ly eco­nom­ic thinkers, that were real­ly more philoso­phers, who thought about the econ­o­my as this vast project of how do we think about well­be­ing? How do we think about hap­pi­ness? How do we all think about our dif­fer­ent roles with­in the econ­o­my as a reflec­tion of the soci­ety that we’re try­ing to cre­ate?

So, that’s where I guess my real inter­est in the econ­o­my came from, was real­ly a rebel­lion toward sort of tra­di­tion­al eco­nom­ics. And got more and more think­ing around peo­ple that are mar­gin­al­ized from the core econ­o­my. People that tra­di­tion­al econ­o­mists and eco­nom­ic his­to­ri­ans don’t real­ly look at. And so that brought me into con­ver­sa­tion with gang­sters, with polit­i­cal agi­ta­tors, with peo­ple on the fringes, basi­cal­ly, try­ing to under­stand what what are those moti­va­tions? We have this idea of sort of ratio­nal self‐interest with­in eco­nom­ics. But how dif­fer­ent cul­tures and dif­fer­ent kinds of economies get cre­at­ed around the world with­in the black mar­ket sys­tem, or with the infor­mal econ­o­my?

Aengus Anderson: What about the tra­di­tion­al econ­o­my or tra­di­tion­al eco­nom­ic the­o­ry? Which of course those things seem like they’re prob­a­bly not even that close­ly relat­ed, but—

Clay: Yeah

Anderson: —we’ll talk about them as if they were. And then we can break apart lat­er if we want. But the tra­di­tion­al econ­o­my. What about that seemed like it need­ed to be cri­tiqued to you?

Clay: I think at a fun­da­men­tal lev­el I just believe in human agency. And I think that every­one should feel like they can par­tic­i­pate and shape the econ­o­my, rather than feel like they’re expe­ri­enc­ing symp­toms of the econ­o­my. When the reces­sion hap­pened, there was all this chat­ter around well, the Fed is going to do this. Or the banks are going to do this. And gov­ern­ment is going to do this. And there was no nar­ra­tive around what peo­ple are going to do. Or how we could sort of rise up togeth­er and do things a bit dif­fer­ent­ly in terms of man­u­fac­tur­ing, or in terms of alter­na­tive ener­gy, or in terms of build­ing more resilient com­mu­ni­ties. There was just…there wasn’t that kind of con­ver­sa­tion hap­pen­ing. And so I think my inter­est is real­ly in broad­en­ing the idea of the econ­o­my so that more peo­ple can feel like they’re includ­ed in the con­ver­sa­tion.

Anderson: Why do you think the econ­o­my seems like this kind of deus ex machi­na thing that’s just kind of doing stuff off in the dis­tance and we’re vic­tims of?

Clay: From a his­tor­i­cal per­spec­tive, it hasn’t always been that way. A lot of peo­ple point to the sort of…this mar­gin­al turn, right. When peo­ple became real­ly pre­oc­cu­pied with this idea of util­i­ty. And towards the end of the 19th cen­tu­ry when econ­o­mists real­ly began to be focused far more on tak­ing ideas from sci­ence, from dis­ci­plines like physics, and apply­ing them to eco­nom­ics. And so as eco­nom­ics tried to become more sci­en­tif­ic and play the game of parad­ing itself around as a sci­ence, it real­ly lost the abil­i­ty to actu­al­ly cater to a more ground­ed, human kind of con­ver­sa­tion. A con­ver­sa­tion about dis­tri­b­u­tion of resources. A con­ver­sa­tion about how we should sort of run our indus­tries or think about inno­va­tion. It became much more math­e­mat­i­cal dur­ing that time.

Anderson: How does that math­e­mat­i­cal for­mu­la actu­al­ly apply to what’s going on in the real world? Does it describe it rea­son­ably well?

Clay: I don’t think it does. I think it depends who you talk to. I’ve always been real­ly sus­pi­cious of dis­ci­plines that try and dis­tance them­selves so much from what they’re study­ing, this sort of move towards objec­tiv­i­ty to me, when you’re with­in a dis­ci­pline that real­ly touch­es people’s lives. Interest rates cor­re­late with our own moods, for exam­ple.

So, one of the biggest things that inter­ests me about the econ­o­my is this rela­tion­ship between these mas­sive trends and how we feel as peo­ple at an indi­vid­ual lev­el. I think most peo­ple, when they feel things that they think are real­ly subjective—you know, they have all these dif­fer­ent kinds of emo­tion­al states. I think a lot of that is tied to eco­nom­ic events that are out­side of their con­trol. And there’s not a real­ly good under­stand­ing of how these dynam­ics work togeth­er. How these objec­tive phe­nom­e­na begin to influ­ence our sub­jec­tive well­be­ing.

The best exam­ple is per­haps look­ing at ideas of con­sump­tion. So, you can look at objec­tive indi­ca­tors of what it means for us to be in the sort of age of affluen­za, or this consumption‐based soci­ety, and you can see that under those con­di­tions peo­ple become more short‐termis. You can see that play out in terms of the kinds of returns that com­pa­nies are look­ing at, or even sort of hedo­nis­tic things that peo­ple will do, want­i­ng to buy some­thing now rather than wait till lat­er.

Anderson: And that’s in a consumption‐based econ­o­my?

Clay: Yeah.

Anderson: So, you might not see that in a more production‐based econ­o­my?

Clay: Yeah. I think that’s right. I think because of this consumption‐based econ­o­my, you can see increas­es in people’s unhap­pi­ness, right. This has been well doc­u­ment­ed. But I think that’s some­thing that’s real­ly excit[ing] about the econ­o­my that we’re switch­ing into, which is more about this sort of mak­er spir­it. This this idea that every­one can har­ness or become a pro­duc­tive agent with­in the econ­o­my.

And so, I think that sense of not only this idea of mak­ing increas­es hap­pi­ness, but you real­ly belong to some­thing. You feel like you actu­al­ly have a sense of pur­pose. And I think every­one should have that oppor­tu­ni­ty. Everyone should feel a sense of belong­ing, feel like they’re active­ly shap­ing some­thing. That they’re not this pas­sive respon­dent to these eco­nom­ic forces.

Anderson: This makes me think of the fourth per­son I spoke to in this project, who was Colin Camerer, the neu­roe­con­o­mist.

Clay: Yeah

Anderson: We start­ed with a lit­tle bit of neu­roe­co­nom­ics and talk­ing about how clas­si­cal eco­nom­ic the­o­ries don’t take into account psy­chol­o­gy, basi­cal­ly. And that as we are learn­ing more and more about psy­chol­o­gy, we’re able to get a bet­ter sense of how peo­ple make choic­es. Is that some­thing that’s moti­vat­ed your work as well, as you’ve start­ed think­ing about the econ­o­my? Were you influ­enced by neu­roe­co­nom­ics in any way?

Clay: Definitely. I think neu­roe­co­nom­ics is some­thing that owes a lot to his­toric the­o­ries of the mind and the econ­o­my. And so, when you say that psy­chol­o­gy hasn’t real­ly been this bed­fel­low of eco­nom­ics, it real­ly has, and maybe they sort of sep­a­rat­ed and became divid­ed. But back in the 17th and 18th cen­turies, the foun­da­tions of eco­nom­ics was based on psy­chol­o­gy, was based on a lot of rich insight from the sort of moral sci­ences of the time. And I think that’s what’s real­ly inter­est­ing. Because I don’t think you can design an econ­o­my with­out fac­tor­ing in human beings, and with­out fac­tor­ing in how human beings are going to feel with­in a cer­tain sit­u­a­tion.

I think neu­roe­co­nom­ics is pos­si­bly used more for sort of hypo­thet­i­cal sit­u­a­tions. I would fault it for that. It’s more descrip­tive in ambi­tion. So it’s not nec­es­sar­i­ly dis­cov­er­ing new mod­els and how we would actu­al­ly live and be with­in those mod­els. It’s more real­ly try­ing to fal­si­fy cer­tain ideas or under­stand­ings of human beings. But it’s done a lot to say hey, we have empa­thy. But you know, 17th cen­tu­ry thinkers thought we had empa­thy, too.

Anderson: So, we talked about the cur­rent sys­tem lead­ing peo­ple to maybe feel a loss of agency with­in it. I want to flesh that out a lit­tle bit more and get into why that’s not a good thing.

Clay: I think human agency is just crit­i­cal to every­thing we do and all the illu­sions we have about free­dom and choice in democ­ra­cy. And I think what­ev­er it is that I end up doing, and I think what the mis­fit econ­o­my as a project is about, is actu­al­ly the first step in bring­ing human agency back into the equa­tion. Speaking to peo­ple who don’t have a voice in how the cur­rent econ­o­my works and yet are a vital com­po­nent of it.

When you look at agency his­tor­i­cal­ly real­ly, and under­stand all great inno­va­tion is based on this prin­ci­ple of human agency, this idea of inven­tion, a thought occurs to us and we can try and bring it into the world. You know, life is short. We’re only leave here for a lit­tle while. And we all have some kind of respon­si­bil­i­ty to feel like we are con­tribut­ing in some capac­i­ty. So you don’t have to be an ego­ma­ni­a­cal sort of dic­ta­tor to under­stand what human agency is about.

Anderson: It can just pro­vide a type of ground­ing and mean­ing and…

Clay: Yeah.

Anderson: So we’ve got this cri­tique of of the present, with a lack of agency. Let’s move into the pirate economies. The uncon­ven­tion­al economies. Let’s talk about a few of them first.

Clay: So the mis­fit econ­o­my, it’s a label we just made up, real­ly. But it’s a sort of brand or iden­ti­ty that we think is pow­er­ful because for some rea­son every­one feels like an out­sider, at some lev­el. But the exam­ples that we explore in The Misfit Economy are real­ly folks in the black mar­kets, in the infor­mal, in the gray mar­ket economies. And so we talk about 18th cen­tu­ry pirates and under­stood how some of their egal­i­tar­i­an mod­els that they used to gov­ern their pirate ships are things that we could apply today. We were in India and we hung out with gang­sters in Mumbai and real­ly tried to under­stand what is moti­vat­ing them, how the life of a gang­ster was chang­ing, and the kinds of things they thought about.

One of the the best inter­views I had was recent­ly with King Tone, who is no longer allowed to go by that name, but is the leader of the Latin Kings out in New York, for a while. And when he was lead­ing the Latin Kings, he was try­ing to sort of piv­ot it as an orga­ni­za­tion to become much more of a social move­ment. And the cops at the time, the FBI, felt real­ly threat­ened by that. Because they wouldn’t do it on the terms of the gov­ern­ment. And so in prison, he was read­ing a lot of peo­ple like Martin Luther King, peo­ple like Malcolm X. These oth­er kinds of social change heroes, and real­ly learn­ing from them, under­stand­ing from them, try­ing to fig­ure out his place with­in this land­scape. And com­ing out, it’s then hard, because every­one wants him to take up the reins of the gang again and go back to that life. And so he’s now this totally…he’s got this dif­fer­ent iden­ti­ty. And he’s got to fig­ure out for the first time how to play enough by the rules of the sys­tem so that he doesn’t get in trou­ble. That he can sort of prove him­self. While also help­ing par­tic­u­lar­ly youth. Folks that he real­ly iden­ti­fies with. Trying to get them more oppor­tu­ni­ties, par­tic­u­lar­ly eco­nom­ic ones. Trying to get them bet­ter inte­grat­ed into soci­ety. And just know­ing that the like­li­hood of that is very slim.

Anderson: So, what is the eco­nom­ic les­son we learned from him?

Clay: What he teach­es us is real­ly about change man­age­ment. He had inher­it­ed an orga­ni­za­tion. The for­mer leader, King Blood, basi­cal­ly had this rep­u­ta­tion for vio­lence. He had to total­ly rebrand this gang. And he built alliances. He reached out to local civic lead­ers. He reached out to church­es, to all these dif­fer­ent orga­ni­za­tions, to real­ly cre­ate a dif­fer­ent mes­sage behind the Kings.

And what’s inter­est­ing is this start­ed out as a sort of inter­nal task force, this secret inter­nal task force with­in the Latin Kings. This kind of cul­tur­al rev­o­lu­tion, rebrand­ing, with­in the gang. And so it wasn’t him com­ing out say­ing, We need to do this.” But he worked and lis­ten to every dif­fer­ent bor­ough that he was rep­re­sent­ing, to fig­ure out how he could repo­si­tion this gang more along the lines of a cul­tur­al insti­tu­tion.

Anderson: I find it real­ly easy to relate to this sto­ry and go, I can now think of the gang as a com­mer­cial enti­ty,” right, as a busi­ness. But that is me apply­ing my under­stand­ing of the tra­di­tion­al busi­ness econ­o­my to a gang. How would I go the oth­er way around and say here’s some­thing that the gang does dif­fer­ent­ly that I can then apply to the tra­di­tion­al econ­o­my?

Clay: Well, I think one thing—two points, real­ly. One is that gangs, dur­ing their hey­day, they were mas­sive orga­ni­za­tion. A gang is no longer that. A lot of the heads of these orga­ni­za­tions have been tak­en out strate­gi­cal­ly by the FBI. So they’re now much small­er. And they oper­ate much more nim­bly. And so I think you had this mas­sive trend of big gangs, and you’ve seen this trend in big com­pa­nies. And how com­pa­nies are fac­ing sim­i­lar ideas about how they should actu­al­ly sort of down­size or spin off ele­ments. And this isn’t a direct what com­pa­nies can learn from gangs,” but the sort of tra­jec­to­ry of down­siz­ing that gangs have fol­lowed is now one that com­pa­nies are begin­ning to explore.

I think much more inter­est­ing is look­ing at gangs as learn­ing orga­ni­za­tions. Understanding how they learned. They actu­al­ly devel­oped, in the Kings, dif­fer­ent cur­ricu­lum around how to do things, around empow­er­ment, around just ideas, cul­ture. They have a whole reli­gion. And this is some­thing that I think com­pa­nies can apply, too, is actu­al­ly devel­op their capac­i­ty as learn­ing orga­ni­za­tions. And I think the whole approach to cur­ricu­lum devel­op­ment that the Kings had is one that oth­er orga­ni­za­tions could ben­e­fit from. And inter­est­ing­ly, now it’s one that King Tone is think­ing of how he can cre­ate a cur­ricu­lum for youth empow­er­ment, and actu­al­ly devel­op an inter­est­ing kind of pro­gram to do this in New York, and Brooklyn specif­i­cal­ly. So, not being tied to the gang, but it’s an inno­va­tion that hap­pened in the gang that he’s now using as a kind of civic pro­gram.

Anderson: You’ve looked at gangs. You’ve looked at pirates. You’ve looked at prison economies. Is there a cen­tral theme that you’re pulling from them in terms of how they might cri­tique the cur­rent econ­o­my we have? Has that informed your cri­tique of it?

Clay: Definitely. I think the whole thing we’re learn­ing in The Misfit Economy is around a greater spir­it of infor­mal­i­ty. And that’s some­thing that we see that orga­ni­za­tions today are in des­per­ate need of. Because they’ve become far too for­mal­ized and dehu­man­iz­ing, specif­i­cal­ly large cor­po­ra­tions. So, the pen­du­lum towards for­mal­iza­tion has just become far too strict. I think one of the great­est flaws with a lot of orga­ni­za­tions is they tend to cod­i­fy rules or prin­ci­ples that make sense for cer­tain deci­sion sce­nar­ios with­in a con­text. And then the con­text fades, and you still have that rule. It’s like junk DNA, except it’s still sort of infect­ing the cur­rent log­ic of the orga­ni­za­tion.

Anderson: Some of the con­ver­sa­tions I’ve had in this series have real­ly got­ten into the under­ly­ing log­ic of mar­kets and of cap­i­tal­ism. And when I think about these mis­fit economies, it seems like they fit into that pret­ty well. They’re just like small­er ver­sions of big­ger cor­po­ra­tions. But it’s the same under­ly­ing mind­set of com­pe­ti­tion and get­ting ahead. Or am I mis­char­ac­ter­iz­ing them.

Clay: I think cap­i­tal­ism isn’t this sort of mono­lith­ic thing. Capitalisms, plur­al, sort of exists. And so even with­in mis­fit economies, you find in cer­tain instances some­one is entire­ly self­ish in a sit­u­a­tion, par­tic­u­lar­ly when it involves drugs. Like, you can see ways in which peo­ple are moti­vat­ed by mon­ey, and that’s a huge moti­va­tion. When we look at hack­er com­mu­ni­ties, you can see oth­er moti­va­tions at work.

Saul: I don’t think there’s one mod­el where you can say, These economies are con­form­ing to one sort of ide­al type that we have for cap­i­tal­ism at large.” But I think what’s inter­est­ing through The Misfit Economy is to explore all the diver­si­ty of economies that are real­ly out there and actu­al­ly see them reflect­ed in the main­stream econ­o­my, too. You know, it’s not like in the mis­fit econ­o­my is this total­ly oth­er sys­tem that we haven’t heard of. We’re all human beings, and economies evolve based on the design con­straint of the fact that we’re human.

And I wouldn’t even say that they’re all— You know, there are cer­tain mis­fit economies that are utter­ly sort of Marxist or offer some grand alter­na­tive. But yeah, I think they are small tweaks, or dif­fer­ent ways they think about gov­er­nance or moti­va­tion that can some­times be help­ful as a mir­ror to our cur­rent sys­tem.

Anderson: Wes Jackson was a thinker who I spoke to. We got into growth, and the fal­la­cy of growth; at some point lim­it­less growth in a finite sys­tem. Is there just a mad­ness in the genet­ics of our tra­di­tion­al eco­nom­ic sys­tem, where it kind of doesn’t know how to stop grow­ing. Like, to stop grow­ing would lead us to a ter­ri­ble eco­nom­ic prob­lem. Do these infor­mal economies or mis­fit economies help us with that, or are they fol­low­ing the same pat­terns of con­tin­u­al growth that the large econ­o­my is.

Clay: Yeah, and I think the growth con­ver­sa­tion is one that is real­ly inter­est­ing. I think par­tic­u­lar­ly when we look at dif­fer­ent kinds of com­mu­ni­ties that get formed, every­one defines progress dif­fer­ent­ly. And so if you believe in growth as a kind of progress, then you sign up for that game. But cer­tain­ly in the mis­fit econ­o­my there are oth­er games at work that peo­ple play by.

You know, hack­ers play by very—you know, it’s not like they’re try­ing to sort of grow, per se. Pirates, cer­tain­ly there’s a sense that booty, or increased rev­enue is a good thing. But they don’t have quite the same vari­ables around growth. And cer­tain­ly with gangs, you see gangs real­ly down­siz­ing and not want­i­ng to grow at the same lev­el. And it’s impos­si­ble now, real­ly, to often dis­tin­guish between social cap­i­tal and and gangs, because gangs have just become these sort of com­mu­ni­ty net­works.

There are def­i­nite­ly alter­na­tives to growth. I think the chal­lenge with growth, which is this awful pari­ah that every­one is plugged into, is to real­ly under­stand the alter­na­tive there. But it’s just so hard because growth is the game that every­one is play­ing. And you real­ly need to be able to make an alter­na­tive that is appeal­ing to peo­ple to get them to jump. From a psy­cho­log­i­cal per­spec­tive, if you have too much tech­no­log­i­cal inno­va­tion or too much growth, peo­ple don’t adapt well. If you have too slow growth, peo­ple feel very stag­nant. So it affects peo­ple at a per­son­al lev­el.

Anderson: Do you think they feel stag­nant because we’re sort of con­di­tioned to expect it? I’m think­ing like, if we were to tele­port into the Middle Ages, would they have felt stag­nant?

Clay: Probably not, right, because you’re liv­ing for the after­world. So the idea of growth, your ori­en­ta­tion to it, real­ly depends on your rela­tion­ship with time and where you put your empha­sis. And I think a lot of cul­tures around the world today wouldn’t even abide by the same idea or sense of progress that we have.

And even in eco­nom­ics, it’s real­ly the most crass kind of progress that we’re look­ing for. We’re not look­ing for spir­i­tu­al progress. We’re not look­ing for growth and wis­dom, you know. We’re real­ly look­ing at growth in the worst terms, even in the most short‐termist kinds of terms.

Anderson: So, there have been lots of peo­ple in this con­ver­sa­tion, the big con­ver­sa­tion of the project, throw­ing out dif­fer­ent ideas of progress. What’s your idea of progress?

Clay: I always real­ly resent­ed this idea of this sort of sense of there being a kind of telos that we’re sort of evolv­ing towards. This idea that there was some­thing uni­form­ly, nor­ma­tive­ly, bet­ter to strive for. I don’t think I have one defined idea of progress. I think at an inter­per­son­al lev­el, I like to be around or meet peo­ple that I think have real­ly com­mit­ted to their own evo­lu­tion and explo­ration, and feel sort of enriched. But I almost like anti‐progress, in a lot of ways. I think under­stand­ing and pre­serv­ing those things that you don’t know makes for bet­ter knowl­edge, and for a bet­ter kind of per­son to be around. And I think we’re all so rushed—

Anderson: What do you mean by that?

Clay: Um, it’s kind of— I mean that’s the nature of Socratic wis­dom, real­ly, is just pre­serve those blind spots, you know. You need to pre­serve your igno­rance, and under­stand and bring empha­sis to those places where you are igno­rant, because that’s what makes you a bet­ter human being, a bet­ter decision‐maker. We spend so much time try­ing to fig­ure every­thing out, and so lit­tle time actu­al­ly just con­tem­plat­ing things that we real­ly don’t know. And that’s real­ly impor­tant.

And keep­ing those lev­els of uncer­tain­ty, I think that’s where every­thing comes from. I love the sort of Amish kind of fig­ure. Or some­one who could see progress more by the rela­tion­ships that they’re mak­ing, or all these oth­er ways, against this idea of tech­no­log­i­cal progress, or some­one who thinks we’re at the height of civ­i­liza­tion. I just don’t think that’s fair. I guess I can’t believe in progress because I have a belief in just fair­ness. And I feel like every­one should be enti­tled to their own idea of progress. And not even progress, but just be able to feel like they can cre­ate their own stan­dards for what’s impor­tant to them.

I don’t know. What would you think? Would you have an idea about where you’re try­ing to progress? I mean, it’s inter­est­ing, too. Like, even things like this. Often these kinds of radio shows or exper­i­ments that one takes, the less agen­da you have the bet­ter off you’re going to do. And so, if you can aban­don the idea of progress for some­thing like this, it often just…right?

Anderson: I com­plete­ly agree. I mean, that’s one of the lux­u­ries of being able to work on a project like this. And one of the rea­sons I sort of want­ed it to be the weird for­mat that it is. Because that makes explor­ing a lot of these things, on their own terms, eas­i­er.

One of the things that I like about the series is it’s putting forth a lot of ideas of types of progress. Normally, talk about in terms of the good. What is the good, and how do you have a prac­ti­cal society‐wide con­ver­sa­tion about the good? Does it always boil down to an ara­tional assump­tion (and whether you call that your notion of progress, or your notion of the good, or val­ue). And if it boils down to those, as it seems to do every time, can you have con­ver­sa­tion? And does con­ver­sa­tion mat­ter?

Clay: And that’s what eco­nom­ic should be about. I mean, it’s one’s rela­tion­ship with the good. The econ­o­my is about a sys­tem of pro­vid­ing us with basic things so that we can live the good life. And then that becomes cor­rupt­ed by econ­o­mists to be this thing called util­i­ty. Which becomes then increas­ing­ly abstract­ed. But it’s real­ly that con­ver­sa­tion. Yeah, what is your rela­tion­ship? What are you try­ing to max­i­mize?

Anderson: I spent a lot of time think­ing about the phi­los­o­phy under­neath eco­nom­ics. But not as eco­nom­ics being or need­ing to be in some way con­ver­sa­tion that is innate­ly philo­soph­i­cal. But I guess if you’re talk­ing about the dis­tri­b­u­tion of goods, then—

Clay: But it’s what you val­ue, right?

Anderson: Right. Right. And that’s… It’s that interesting—like the dou­ble use of the word val­ue,” right? It is both the val­ue with­in the econ­o­my, the val­ue as a moral thing with­in one’s under­stand­ing of the world. This makes me think of of the con­ver­sa­tion I was hav­ing with Douglas Rushkoff about quan­tifi­ca­tion. Going back to our more clas­si­cal eco­nom­ics the­o­ries, which quan­ti­fy a lot of things. And when those the­o­ries start to real­ly become nor­mal­ized every­where and you stop see­ing them as the­o­ries, and it just…the quan­tifi­ca­tion of eco­nom­ics, always think­ing in terms of price or quan­ti­ty, that can bleed over into quan­ti­fy­ing a lot of oth­er things. And maybe that makes it hard­er to have that con­ver­sa­tion about progress, about those oth­er forms of progress.

Clay: This debate also hap­pens a lot with­in the NGO world, social entre­pre­neur­ship, what­ev­er you want to call it. As peo­ple try and think not only how do you mea­sure things like num­bers, prof­its, etc., but how do you mea­sure the good that you’re cre­at­ing. Maybe you’re sav­ing the envi­ron­ment, or you’re sav­ing” peo­ple of some dis­ease, or what­ev­er. How do you begin to mea­sure that? And I think the chal­lenge there is, once you begin to quan­ti­fy things, you intro­duce an idea of progress to a pro­gram, right. Because then you mea­sure your­self against things that you begin to mea­sure. So, you have these num­bers that then take pow­er away from peo­ple to actu­al­ly begin to change ele­ments of the pro­gram.

Yeah, I mean, I think quan­ti­fy­ing can be real­ly dan­ger­ous. But at oth­er times it can be real­ly help­ful. I remem­ber I had this cool con­ver­sa­tion with David Harvey, who’s a Marxist. I can have a Marxist moment, you know? But I could nev­er just ful­ly be with­in a sort of Marxist per­spec­tive. And we were talk­ing about wet­lands. And I was talk­ing about some­one I knew that was doing his best to quan­ti­fy nature. So, look­ing at how you could basi­cal­ly cre­ate a sense of the wet­lands’ val­ue to this com­mu­ni­ty. And he was quan­ti­fy­ing, quan­ti­fy­ing. And he even­tu­al­ly end­ed up sav­ing these wet­lands, because he could show, in an eco­nom­ic argu­ment, their big­ger val­ue to this com­mu­ni­ty.

And Dave Harvey thought that was an inter­est­ing exam­ple, but he also thought it was cap­i­tal­ism tak­ing over nature. Now nature needs a val­ue. And with­in the Marxist lens, every­thing becomes sort of com­mod­i­fied, right. So now he’s doing this with nature, to defend it. Sure, it defends it. Maybe that’s a small vic­to­ry in the present. But it’s just part of this big­ger nar­ra­tive where every­thing is get­ting quan­ti­fied and giv­en num­bers to.

Anderson: Hm. I would think—and maybe this is just me show­ing my ignorance—that a Marxist per­spec­tive would be influ­enced by a lot of the same val­ues. Because ulti­mate­ly if you real­ly want to jus­ti­fy sav­ing the wet­lands, you can do it in a way… So, I was talk­ing to this this geo­engi­neer, David Keith, and he was talk­ing about, look we can we can talk about sav­ing nature all day long. And he’s like, I can give you these var­i­ous anthro­pocen­tric argu­ments for why it’s in your best inter­est.” But he’s like, real­ly you just want to save it because you want to save it, go out, be in it, done.

Clay: Yeah.

Anderson: And I would think that Marxism, like a more cap­i­tal­ist approach to the wet­lands, would kind of still see it in mate­r­i­al terms. Because that oth­er thing, that go be in nature thing, is com­ing from a total­ly dif­fer­ent, ara­tional space, right. It’s a spir­i­tu­al atti­tude towards the envi­ron­ment, which can coex­ist with Marxism or cap­i­tal­ism, but isn’t part of either of those things.

Clay: But I think— So, I total­ly agree. But I think Harvey’s point is he brings cap­i­tal and space. He has all these real­ly inter­est­ing ways of look­ing at ways in which cap­i­tal comes to dom­i­nate our inter­ac­tion with a giv­en space. And so that nature only has val­ue because it’s plugged into this frame of ref­er­ence, it’s becom­ing increas­ing­ly quan­ti­fied and we look at it through eco­nom­ic val­ue. And I think it’s ulti­mate­ly, for him, encroach­ment, real­ly. This comes to pen­e­trate all of our lives. And the big sort of Venn dia­grams that a Marxist would look through is his­tor­i­cal­ly we had this big cir­cle of soci­ety. And econ­o­my was a small cir­cle with­in soci­ety. And soci­ety cre­at­ed norms. And the econ­o­my was just local mar­kets; it wasn’t that big. And now we have, today, this big cir­cle of econ­o­my and the small cir­cle of soci­ety. And the eco­nom­ic sys­tem that we live in informs so much of our norms, behav­iors, etc. And that tran­si­tion is a rough one, because it means that you can’t pro­gram the econ­o­my in the same way. That you used to be able to sort of con­trol soci­ety, and its norms, and its morals, etc. You don’t have that same con­trol, because soci­ety is being mar­gin­al­ized.

Anderson: Which is a real­ly strange flip on its head. And it also seems like when you do that flip, when the eco­nom­ic sphere becomes big­ger in some ways than dif­fer­ent social spheres, how do you then address the eco­nom­ic sphere, right? I mean, it’s become real­i­ty. It’s become invis­i­ble in so many ways, you know.

Clay: It’s inter­est­ing to look at it say, through mar­riage, right. Marriage is some­thing where we would have…or even dat­ing. We would think about it through these terms of courtship, of meet­ing some­one. People write poet­ry about it. There are all of these feel­ings there. It’s some­thing very spe­cial. But you can also look at it through a mar­ket per­spec­tive, right. And increas­ing­ly you see ways in which mar­kets are com­ing to deter­mine who peo­ple end up with—

Anderson: Oh my God.

Clay: —and how peo­ple mar­ry. In India for The Misfit Economy, we met a lot of match­mak­ers, which was super inter­est­ing. We were stay­ing at one guy’s house, and some­one deliv­ered this resume at his door. And it was basi­cal­ly a mar­riage pro­pos­al. It was the first step of a mar­riage pro­pos­al. And I was in New York recent­ly and hung out with some­one who had a whole Excel matrix with dif­fer­ent guys list­ed that she’d dat­ed, and she was doing a sort of com­par­a­tive analy­sis. She was from a finance back­ground. But to me that’s real­ly scary. You can see the ways in which mar­ket log­ics are creep­ing into pri­vate life. And so deci­sions that used to be about oth­er things. Are now very much…have been grasped by the mar­ket.

Anderson: And so what I won­der is, here we are talk­ing also about the big Conversation, with the cap­i­tals, where we’re hop­ing to have a bet­ter future with a lot of dif­fer­ent peo­ple. And how do you have the Conversation in a world where quan­ti­fied think­ing is so nat­u­ral­ized? Where you have a spread­sheet of dif­fer­ent peo­ple who you will spend your life with, maybe. And that if you don’t feel that way, where’s the com­mon lan­guage?

Clay: Is your fear that peo­ple who devel­op a more insu­lar kind of cul­ture, they’re not going to be able to speak to one anoth­er?

Anderson: That may be some of it.

Clay: Yeah.

Anderson: And the oth­er part of it may be that there’s actu­al­ly noth­ing to talk about.

Clay: I think you can bridge those things. I think peo­ple are liv­ing in ide­olo­gies, right. And so the point of con­ver­sa­tion is to sort of strip us of those ide­olo­gies and human desires. You know, those haven’t changed much. You can look back at ancient times and you can see that peo­ple pret­ty much had all the same emo­tions, were talk­ing about basi­cal­ly the same things. So, I think it’s real­ly just the abil­i­ty to decon­struct ide­olo­gies, and to do that through real­ly hon­est and direct con­ver­sa­tion. And I think what’s scari­er is peo­ple can’t real­ly see them­selves as dif­fer­ent from the ide­ol­o­gy that they take on.

Anderson: You know, what I was talk­ing about with Lawrence, the philoso­pher, was enlight­en­ment lib­er­al­ism, in the most opti­mistic, pos­i­tive way you could pos­si­bly imag­ine. Saying, look we’ve got this plu­ral­is­tic com­mu­ni­ties. What do you do? Well, you have to agree on some def­i­n­i­tion of being rea­son­able. To be will­ing to enter into con­ver­sa­tion with­out the use of force. That was his low­est lev­el good.

Clay: But, right so you’ve exclud­ed now like, ter­ror­ists. Or all these oth­ers, poten­tial­ly.

Anderson: Right. And he acknowl­edged that. And that’s kind of the ten­sion in that whole strain of thought. Like, say you want to have a rea­soned con­ver­sa­tion with a fun­da­men­tal­ist. For them to engage in that con­ver­sa­tion with you, they have to be more of a lib­er­al than a fun­da­men­tal­ist. So, essen­tial­ly to have that con­ver­sa­tion with them, they have to be…you.

Clay: And I think the oth­er— I mean the whole con­struct is kind of Rawlsian, right? Like, you have this—

Anderson: We talked a lot about Rawls.

Clay: Okay. Yeah, I real­ly don’t— The British…I did school in England, and they make you read a lot of Rawls, too. But I nev­er liked it. It’s so hypo­thet­i­cal. It’s just so like, Okay, let’s all use this same delib­er­a­tive ratio­nal­i­ty and agree on the ways in which we would come togeth­er in con­sen­sus.” And I think from a gov­ern­ment stand­point it’s real­ly dif­fi­cult to say this is the one for­mu­la” that we want to sort of take.

There’s this fun­ny book with­in eco­nom­ic his­to­ry. It’s called The Passions and the Interests. And it basi­cal­ly describes the sit­u­a­tion under which some­one that might try and beat you up instead—because you have money—just wants your coin purse, and how mon­ey or cap­i­tal­ism actu­al­ly comes to tame the pas­sions. I think you can say maybe a lot of the sort of vio­lent dri­ves that we have have sort of been sub­li­mat­ed towards these cap­i­tal­ist pur­suits.

Anderson: Does that rely on most peo­ple hav­ing enough to lose that they don’t resort to vio­lence?

Clay: Right.

Anderson: Like, a floor of afflu­ence, basi­cal­ly. And if you fall beneath that floor of afflu­ence, then our mar­ket soci­ety is not going to pla­cate you.

Clay: I think you can see that with ter­ror­ism, right. A University of Chicago pro­fes­sor looked into this, but basi­cal­ly showed that those who sought refuge in ter­ror­ism were real­ly ones that were eco­nom­i­cal­ly mar­gin­al­ized. It grew so fast in areas that hadn’t been part of sig­nif­i­cant wealth gains in the Middle East, who hadn’t been part of that oil mon­ey, exact­ly. Certainly there are lead­ers that don’t fit that descrip­tion, but on the whole you see that it was real­ly eco­nom­i­cal­ly moti­vat­ed. And in a lot of areas, it’s sort of sad­den­ing the degree to which being eco­nom­i­cal­ly includ­ed, and hav­ing access to that income, can sub­due a lot of the great pas­sions that peo­ple have. If it takes them away from vio­lence, it’s prob­a­bly a good thing.

But it also—just get­ting back from a trip to China—it’s so dystopi­an over there. Everyone that I met in—you know, I didn’t go to the West of the coun­try, which is a bit more cul­tur­al­ly intact. But in Beijing and Shanghai, it’s the pur­suit of mon­ey. There aren’t real­ly many oth­er things that peo­ple are think­ing about.

Anderson: You men­tioned a moment ago some sort of cau­tious opti­mism. On the whole, are you opti­mistic about the future?

Clay: Yeah, I think so. I’ve seen signs of things com­ing recent­ly that have the real pow­er to be trans­for­ma­tive. It’s fun­ny, I was talk­ing to some­one who’s in her fifties and mon­i­tors East London, which is a very hip­ster kind of area. And she basi­cal­ly said, The hip­sters are cur­ing their apa­thy through knit­ting.” And you can see the growth that these kinds of hob­by­ist art forms with­in these com­mu­ni­ties that used to be large­ly apa­thet­ic youth, as a gen­tle sign of opti­mism. But it’s also like, this whole mak­er spir­it is some­thing that I am tremen­dous­ly excit­ed about. I think we’re going to do man­u­fac­tur­ing, and think about pro­duc­tion, in very dif­fer­ent ways, and it’s going to become much more democ­ra­tized.

And this idea of a cit­i­zen sec­tor. This idea that we won’t have to be depen­dent on large cor­po­ra­tions to pro­vide us with things. That we can cer­tain­ly learn from them, but that they’ll either have to sort of evolve rapid­ly and become more agile and nim­ble and embed­ded in com­mu­ni­ties and soci­eties, or they’ll real­ly have to go extinct. That’s one trend that I’m see­ing. But cer­tain­ly there are a lot of oth­er big kinds of trends out there that could total­ly ham­per it. And being in China, none of what we’re doing here mat­ters at all. Basically, what­ev­er China does and locks into, from the per­spec­tive of the econ­o­my and the envi­ron­ment, is how the future is going to be guid­ed. A lot of our real­i­ty will be deter­mined just because of the sheer size of pop­u­la­tion, and the fact that we’ve been sell­ing off our econ­o­my to them. So, yeah. I mean, I think opti­mism but also like oth­er vari­ables at work.

Anderson: Does con­ver­sa­tion mat­ter?

Clay: Definitely. I mean it’s all about con­ver­sa­tion when, par­tic­u­lar­ly insti­tu­tions, have such hack­neyed lan­guage. And the moment that you start talk­ing about some­thing real, peo­ple sort of light up. I haven’t worked with cor­po­rates very much. But when I do it’s almost like ther­a­py for them. That’s the only ser­vice that I would ever pro­vide as a con­sul­tant, is the abil­i­ty for them to think in a fresh lan­guage about what they’re doing. And to begin to sort of reimag­ine what they could do with the resources that they have.

We deter­mine our ideas of progress with lan­guage. We deter­mine nar­ra­tives that act to guide us, that moti­vate us. And stum­bling upon a new kind of phrase can just open up entire­ly new pos­si­bil­i­ties. And that’s what hap­pens with the econ­o­my, and that’s why con­ver­sa­tion about the econ­o­my is so impor­tant. Because if you can get one per­son to reframe some­thing, or to think about some­thing slight­ly dif­fer­ent, it can be real­ly trans­for­ma­tion­al.

What is it that you want to achieve? What is it that you want to val­ue? It’s our sort of first line of defense as human beings. It’s what we can sort of pre­serve our­self against the mas­sive forces of cap­i­tal­ism and of cor­po­rate pol­i­tics and things like that is, lan­guage is the thing that can cut through all that.


Aengus Anderson: Well, we’ve worked through this one a cou­ple of times and it’s real­ly taxed our eco­nom­ics vocab­u­lary. So here goes. This is num­ber five, and were rolling.

We’re talk­ing about the econ­o­my in a real­ly big way here. I think prob­a­bly one of my favorite things Alexa does is she talks about the econ­o­my as a moral philo­soph­i­cal issue.

Micah Saul: Right. Comes from our own moral­i­ty and is the engine for dis­pens­ing the good life, what­ev­er that means.

Anderson: Kind of the mate­r­i­al side­kick of all of our lofty fan­tasies of what a soci­ety should look like.

Saul: Or at least that’s how it start­ed.

Anderson: But it cer­tain­ly doesn’t seem there now, does it? I mean, I don’t find a lot of moral phi­los­o­phy in the Wall Street Journal’s busi­ness report­ing.

Saul: Or the Financial Times.

Anderson: So, that’s bro­ken apart. And now I think Alexa’s argu­ing, pret­ty per­sua­sive­ly, the economy’s treat­ed as a thing of its own, hav­ing its own rules, its own log­ic. It’s a game that we made and we for­got that we can make it any way we want, almost.

Saul: It’s become one of those big sys­tems that we talk about through­out this project. It’s too com­plex and inter­con­nect­ed and ouroboros‐like for any human to actu­al­ly wrap their brain around it.

Anderson: And the upshot of that being that it’s real­ly hard to feel like you’ve got a lot of agency. At least unless you’re at the very top, right?

Saul: Right.

Anderson: Most peo­ple don’t feel like they can real­ly change the eco­nom­ic mod­el. And they’re right. That’s the oth­er part. They are right in feel­ing dis­em­pow­ered. So what’s bad about the loss of agency? I mean, she talks specif­i­cal­ly about, you feel dis­em­pow­ered as a per­son. That makes you unhap­py. So there’s a psy­cho­log­i­cal aspect of it.

Saul: I think there’s an inter­est­ing sort of vicious cycle there, where if you feel dis­em­pow­ered, you are less inclined to try to exert any agency over it, and it’s going to get far­ther and far­ther from its moral or philo­soph­i­cal roots.

Anderson: Until you’re los­ing at the hands of the econ­o­my so bad­ly that you have to be an agent. Well, and that’s where you get a mis­fit econ­o­my. You get an econ­o­my for peo­ple who are out­side of the tra­di­tion­al econ­o­my. It isn’t serv­ing them, and they are…they’re still agents. They are cre­at­ing their own sys­tems out there on the periph­ery.

Saul: it’s kind of cool that she diag­noses this larg­er sense of dis­en­fran­chise­ment, and then kind of looks at the few places where you can find peo­ple who are not pow­er­ful who are agents. We should real­ly con­nect to Gabe Stempinski’s con­ver­sa­tion here.

Saul: Yes.

Anderson: With the shar­ing econ­o­my. And a lot of lis­ten­er com­ments were peo­ple who felt that while the shar­ing econ­o­my may be a great idea, it was not the Conversation with the cap­i­tals because it was sort of an adjust­ment to the sta­tus quo rather than a real­ly new idea. It wasn’t a cri­tique of the growth sys­tem. It wouldn’t ulti­mate­ly lead to any­thing more than maybe the Jevons para­dox, cre­at­ing greater effi­cien­cy in how we use resources, thus allow­ing us to grow fur­ther.

And you know, as we talk about mis­fit economies, I think we need to keep our lis­ten­ers’ cri­tique there in mind and ask, do these mis­fit economies real­ly rep­re­sent anoth­er type of mod­el, or are they iter­a­tions upon the kind of sta­tus quo that we’ve heard pret­ty thor­ough­ly beat­en up by thinkers from Korten to Jackson. People who real­ly crit­i­cize the growth sys­tem.

Saul: You touch on that some in your con­ver­sa­tion with Alexa, but I don’t know that that was answered. I’m gonna take a quick detour, which I think is also going to get us to that same ques­tion, which is anoth­er con­nec­tion to Colin Camerer.

Anderson: Back in episode four.

Saul: All of…eight months ago?

Anderson: Yeah.

Saul: So, for those that don’t remem­ber or maybe haven’t lis­tened, Colin Camerer is a neu­roe­con­o­mist at Caltech. So, Alexa is very aware of neu­roe­co­nom­ics. But she feels it’s too the­o­ret­i­cal.

Anderson: Yeah, I think the biggest part of that, real­ly, is where she feels that it’s descrip­tive. It looks at a sys­temic and goes kind of, Here’s how we oper­ate. Here’s how the econ­o­my oper­ates. Okay, those things are dif­fer­ent.” Well, that’s a pret­ty for­mi­da­ble cri­tique, but it doesn’t real­ly give you a new sys­tem. It doesn’t lead to a big moral con­ver­sa­tion about jus­tice. It doesn’t get you sort of the mas­sive change that she seems to want from the mis­fit economies.

Saul: Right. I’m going to turn that around, though, and and ask are these mis­fit economies offer­ing that fun­da­men­tal new idea? Or are they just the larg­er econ­o­my writ small?

Anderson: I think there are a cou­ple ways we can go about it. First, we can say well, she gives us two exam­ples where we’re talk­ing about the Latin kings. We’re talk­ing about first, gangs as a whole down­siz­ing, get­ting more nim­ble. That’s a trend that cor­po­ra­tions can fol­low. To me, that seems like an adjust­ment. That’s not a sea change in oper­a­tions. So we can set that one aside.

Now, mis­fit economies as learn­ing orga­ni­za­tions, that’s kind of inter­est­ing. But is it a sea change in how we think about the econ­o­my? Is hav­ing a dif­fer­ent and more flex­i­ble struc­ture for adap­ta­tion and change in say, a gang or a prison econ­o­my or a pirate econ­o­my… If you applied that to a cor­po­ra­tion and you had an incred­i­bly nim­ble cor­po­ra­tion, does that real­ly change the big pic­ture? Does it say, undo the growth mod­el?

Saul: I think it cer­tain­ly has the poten­tial to, per­haps. But I don’t see a causal link between a more nim­ble learn­ing econ­o­my and…therefore not not based on growth.

Anderson: And maybe we’re com­ing into this with a false assump­tion that the growth econ­o­my is a prob­lem.

Saul: I guess that’s an impor­tant thing that we inform lis­ten­ers when our bias­es are becom­ing very appar­ent, we should rec­og­nize them and point them out. I too have been very con­vinced by peo­ple like Wes Jackson that our cur­rent mod­el of growth is unsus­tain­able and dan­ger­ous.

The thing is, that actu­al­ly is not nec­es­sar­i­ly what Alexa said, any­where in this con­ver­sa­tion. To be com­ing at it from that angle, we just need to make it very clear that that’s what we are think­ing about.

Anderson: At the same time, even if that was the goal—and I do think that’s an impor­tant ques­tion that needs to be answered—some of the oth­er economies that we didn’t get into in this con­ver­sa­tion might offer bet­ter clues than say, a gang econ­o­my. We didn’t real­ly get into the depths of like, what does a hack­er econ­o­my look like? Is that a dif­fer­ent econ­o­my? Does that embody dif­fer­ent val­ue choic­es? I don’t think we real­ly know. Then maybe this is just a lack of my own imag­i­na­tion. I real­ly don’t know if these mis­fit economies are the mod­el for that sort of mas­sive change. I can see them tak­ing us towards more agency. I can see them tak­ing us towards local com­mu­ni­ties.

Saul: Right.

Anderson: Which are hav­ing much greater con­trol. So, con­ceiv­ably could have a lot more hap­pi­ness. That seems real­ly laud­able.

Saul: That’s what I want­ed to say, was that Alexa views one of the biggest issues with all cur­rent eco­nom­ic mod­els is that lack of human agency. If these mis­fit economies are solv­ing that issue, that’s where she sees them as being very impor­tant. And offer­ing new change.

Anderson: Can the mis­fit econ­o­my kind of serve as a step­ping stone along this path towards increas­ing human agency first? Which of course increas­es hap­pi­ness, pre­sum­ably. And then gives peo­ple the abil­i­ty to sort of change the larg­er econ­o­my, in a way that seems impos­si­ble now? So maybe the mis­fit econ­o­my itself isn’t going to cri­tique or real­ly over­haul the big econ­o­my. But maybe it will give peo­ple a tool to do that lat­er? I don’t now.

Saul: It’s fun­ny. It makes me think of a con­nec­tion we hadn’t made yet with the the Happiness Initiative.

Anderson: That makes per­fect sense.

Saul: Right? In some ways, this is very much con­nect­ed with that idea. And I think actu­al­ly they’re com­ing from very sim­i­lar places. People are dis­tanced from the econ­o­my. And if we can reframe what the econ­o­my means and what the econ­o­my is sup­posed to do, and include hap­pi­ness and include con­nect­ed­ness, does that pro­vide the tools to solve those broad­er prob­lems that Jackson points out?

Anderson: That’s a good ques­tion. I think it’s also prob­a­bly a good place to leave it. There are a mil­lion more things we could talk about here.

Saul: Yeah.

Anderson: But we can’t have an out­ro that goes on for six hours. Though we would like to. And we will prob­a­bly con­tin­ue this con­ver­sa­tion offline, and you should too. Or con­tin­ue it online, with us.

That was Alexa Clay, record­ed November 1, 2012 in Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Saul: This is The Conversation. You can find us on Twitter at @aengusanderson and on the web at find​the​con​ver​sa​tion​.com

Anderson: So thanks for lis­ten­ing. I’m Aengus Anderson.

Saul: And I’m Micah Saul.

Further Reference

This interview at the Conversation web site, with project notes, comments, and taxonomic organization specific to The Conversation.


Help Support Open Transcripts

If you found this useful or interesting, please consider supporting the project monthly at Patreon or once via Square Cash, or even just sharing the link. Thanks.